(英文)行業(yè)資料IMF-FISCAL MONITOR-April 2023-Chapter 2 Inflation and Disinflation What Role for Fiscal Policy-report 2023-04-06_第1頁(yè)
(英文)行業(yè)資料IMF-FISCAL MONITOR-April 2023-Chapter 2 Inflation and Disinflation What Role for Fiscal Policy-report 2023-04-06_第2頁(yè)
(英文)行業(yè)資料IMF-FISCAL MONITOR-April 2023-Chapter 2 Inflation and Disinflation What Role for Fiscal Policy-report 2023-04-06_第3頁(yè)
(英文)行業(yè)資料IMF-FISCAL MONITOR-April 2023-Chapter 2 Inflation and Disinflation What Role for Fiscal Policy-report 2023-04-06_第4頁(yè)
(英文)行業(yè)資料IMF-FISCAL MONITOR-April 2023-Chapter 2 Inflation and Disinflation What Role for Fiscal Policy-report 2023-04-06_第5頁(yè)
已閱讀5頁(yè),還剩39頁(yè)未讀, 繼續(xù)免費(fèi)閱讀

下載本文檔

版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶(hù)提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)

文檔簡(jiǎn)介

CHAPTER

INFLATIONANDDISINFLATION:WHATROLEFORFISCALPOLICY?

2

Introduction

Theupsurgeininflationthatbeganin2021—thesharpestinmorethanthreedecades—hasaffected

fiscalaccounts,worsenedpoverty,andalteredthe

distributionofhouseholds’well-being,callingon

policymakerstorespond.Thischapteranalyzesthesedevelopmentsandexploreshowfiscalpolicycandoitsparttocurbinflationwhilesupportingthevulnerable.1

Mostpeoplestronglydislikehighandvariable

inflation,2whichcausesmanydistortionsinthe

economy(AgarwalandKimball2022),includinggreateruncertainty.Relativepricesofgoodsandservicesmay

becomeblurred—nolongerreflectingrelativedemandandsupplyconditionsandmakingeverydaydecisionsaboutconsumption,investment,andproduction

decisionsharderforhouseholds,financiers,andfirms.Inflationismorelikelytobecomepersistentif,akintoatug-of-war,eachgroupintheeconomy—employersandworkers,producersandconsumers,andretailersandtheirsuppliers—triestoholdontoitsshareof

prosperityattheexpenseofothers.Ifsuchsocial

tensionsleadtoinconsistentmacroeconomicpolicies(forexample,monetarypolicythatistooloose),highinflationwillpersistlonger,ultimatelyprolongingacostlyphenomenonforeveryone.

Inflationoftenleadstoariseinpovertyfromlossofpurchasingpower(Cardoso1992),and,aswithanyadversity,poorfamiliestendtosuffer

ThischapterwaspreparedbystafffromtheFiscalAffairs

Department.TheauthorsofthischapterareMarcosPoplawski-

Ribeiro(teamlead),CarlosEduardoGon?alves(teamco-lead),

ChadiAbdallah,VybhaviBalasundharam,YongquanCao,DanielGarcia-Macia,AndresGhini,TingLan,AnhDinhMinhNguyen,JuliethPicoMejía,andAlbertoTumino,withresearchsupport

fromKardelenCicek,ArikaKayastha,ZhonghaoWei,andAndrewWomer,andundertheguidanceofPaoloMauroandPauloMedas.

1Althoughthespikeinpricesduring2021–22wasinitially

concentratedinfoodandenergy,thischapterdiscussesinflationmoregenerallyasasustainedriseinthepricesofmanygoods

andservices,whichmayoriginatefromdifferentsources.The

analysismeasuresinflationusingtheConsumerPriceIndex(CPI),complementingitwiththeGDPdeflatorinspecificexercises.Forrecentdevelopmentsontherelationshipbetweeninflationand

publicfinances,seealsoChapter1.

2SeesurveyresultsinShiller(1997),Scheve(2001),andPrati(2022).

disproportionatelymorebecausetheyconsumemore

asshareoftheirincomeandtheylackbuffersinthe

formofaccumulatedsavings.Butthedistributive

effectsofinflationstemmingfromitsunevenimpacts

onthebudgetsofdifferenthouseholdsarefarmore

complex.Inturn,thesedependonvariousfactors,

includingthesourceofpriceincreases(forexample,

foodorenergyprices)andtheirform(demand,

orwagepush);households’consumptionbaskets,

sourcesofincome,andthesizeandcomposition

oftheirbalancesheets(forexample,theirposition

asnetborrowersorlenders);andpolicydesignand

responses(suchasindexationofwages,pensions,

andsocialsafetynets).Governmentpoliciesneedto

beinformedbyanunderstandingofhowinflation

affectsvariousgroupsinsociety.Greateravailability

ofhouseholddatamakesitpossibletoanalyzehow

bigthoseeffectsare,whichchannelsaffectthem,and

howtheyvaryacrosshouseholds.3

Theimpactofinflationonthefiscalaccountsalso

dependsonredistribution—inthiscase,betweenthe

publicsectorandtheprivatesector.Anunexpected

boutofinflationerodesthereal(inflation-adjusted)

valueofpublicdebt,atleastinthenearterm,with

bondholdersbearingtheloss.Likewise,deficit-to-GDP

ratiosdeclinebecausethenominal(currentmonetary)

valuesoftheeconomy’soutputandoftaxbases

willgenerallyrise,generatingmorerevenues,while

spending—oftensetinnominaltermsinthebudget—

initiallyfailstokeepup.Withoutindexation,real

incomesdeclineforcivilservants,pensioners,and

recipientsofwelfaretransfers.Thequalityofpublic

servicesmayalsosufferasnominalspendingceilings

clashwithhighercostsofgoodsandservices.Theearly

declineindeficitsasashareofGDPmaynotlastover

themediumterm;yet,asinflationbecomesexpected,

spendingcatchesup,andthecostofborrowing

risesasinvestorsrequireaninflationriskpremium

3Empiricalanalysesofhistoricalepisodeshavebeenconstrainedby

limitedavailabilityofcomparabledata.Astudybasedonsurveysof

overallincomesofhouseholdsinIsraelwithatleastoneemployee,

fortheperiod1950?91(includingthehyperinflationofthe

mid-1980s),reportsevidenceofastatisticallysignificantcorrelation

betweeninflationandinequalityinincomes(Dahan1996).

InternationalMonetaryFund|April20231

CHAPTER2INFLATIONANddISINFLATION:WhATROLeFORFISCALPOLICy?

indexation(inthiscase,ofthresholds),discussedlaterinthechapter.

.Inertiainnominalspending.Thenetresponse

ofthefiscalbalancestoinflationdependson

whetherexpenditurekeepspacewithrevenues.

Duringthebudgetyear,thisisseldomthecasebecausespendingcapsareusuallysetinnominalterms,althoughindexationofsomeimportant

itemssuchaspublicwagesandtransfersmay

leadinsomecasestoautomaticadjustmentstoinflationinthesameyear.Adhocadjustments

ornewmeasuressuchasintroductionor

enhancementofsubsidies(forexample,in

responsetohigherfoodorenergyprices)canalsospeeduptheriseinnominalspending.

.Sovereigndebtsizeandstructure,andinvestors’

response.Thelargerthedebt,thegreaterthe

potentialerosionfrominflation.Thiseffectis

attenuated,however,ifaportionofthedebtis

inflation-linked(asinflationautomaticallyleads

tohigherborrowingcosts),isdenominatedin

foreigncurrency(asinflationleadstodepreciation,potentiallyresultinginhigherrepaymentswhen

expressedindomesticcurrency),hasafloatingrate(asinflationpromptshigherpolicy,and

hencehighershort-termbenchmarkrates),or

hasagreatershareofshort-termbondsthatarematuringandneedtoberolledover(asinvestorswillaskforhigherratesonnewlyissuedbonds).Whengovernmentsissuenewdebt,investorsmayrequirehigherreturnstocompensatenotonlyforexpectedinflationbutalsoforhigherinflation

volatility(aninflationriskpremium)—and,forcountrieswhereeconomicprospectsareuncertainandthedebtratioremainshighorkeepsrising,adefaultpremium.

InternationalPracticeswithInflationIndexation

Countries’practicesvaryregardinghowmuchtaxorbudgetitemsareindexedtoinflationoradjustedtoinflationbypolicymeasures.Thishasconsequencesforhowtheirpublicfinancesevolveinthefaceof

inflationsurprises.Indexationofpoliticallysalientexpenditureitemssuchaspensionsorwagesisoftenaprominenttopicinpublicdiscourse.Theeffects

ontherevenueside,whilelessdiscussed,arenolessrelevant.Ifincometaxthresholdsarenotadjustedto

inflation,forexample,taxpayersmaybepushedintohighertaxbrackets(bracketcreep),orthevalueof

theirtaxallowancesanddeductionsmaybeeroded.

Thedegreeofindexationinvolvestrade-offs.On

onehand,indexingpublicwages,pensions,orwelfaretransfersreducesuncertaintyandpreservespurchasingpowerforcivilservants,retirees,andlow-income

households.Itmayalsopreventdistortionarygapsbetweenpublicandprivatewagesorapossiblebraindrainfromthepublicsector.Ontheotherhand,

indexationsustainsrealexpenditures,contributingtoaggregatedemandandpotentiallymakinginflationmorepersistent.Ifpublicwagesareabenchmarkforprivatewages(asinmanycountries),indexationofpublicwagescouldprolongwageandinflationary

pressures(Box2.1).Widespreadindexationcanlimitthescopefordiscretionarycuts.

Countrieshavetakendifferentapproachesto

indexationpolicies(Figure2.1).Aminorityof

countriesindexorregularlyadjusttheirincometaxratebracketstominimizebracketcreep.

Indexationismorecommonforsomeimportant

expenditureitems,especiallypensions.Nearlyall

advancedeconomies,about50percentofemerging

marketeconomies,and30percentoflow-income

developingcountrieshavesomeformofindexation.

Pensionindexationhasbecomemoreprevalent

recently,butmanycountrieshavemadeitlessgeneroustoreducetheburdenonthebudgetandsafeguard

thesustainabilityofpensionsystems(OECD2022a).Countrieshavemovedfromwageindexationtoward

priceindexationasnominalwageincreaseshave

tendedtoexceedpriceinflationinthepast,reflectingproductivitygains.5Manycountriesfurtherindex

theirsocialassistanceprograms,witharoundhalfof

advancedeconomieslinkingseveraloftheirbenefitstoinflation(OECD2022c).Bycontrast,mostcountriesdonotindexpublicwagestoinflation—apracticethathasbecomelessprevalentinrecentdecades,perhapsbecauseinflationhadbeenlow.Butthepressure

toindexwagesmayreturnifhighinflationpersists(SuthaharanandBleakley2022).6

5In2022,suchastrategymayhavebeencostlierthanpredictedgiventhatinflationrosefasterthannominalwages(OECD2022d).

6Forpublicwages,theirincreasesinmostcountriestendtoberelatedtothepoliticalcycleratherthantoindexation(Gaspar,Gupta,andMulas-Granados2017).

InternationalMonetaryFund|April20233

FISCALMONITOR:ONThePAThTOPOLICyNORMALIzATION

Figure2.1.IndexationPoliciesVaryacrosstheWorldandacrossBudgetItems

(Percentageofcountriesineachincomegroup)

100

90

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0

1.PersonalIncomeTax

Brackets’Indexation1

Noregularadjustments

Regulardefactoadjustments

Automaticpriceadjustments

100

90

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0

AEs

EMsLIDCs

2.PensionIndexation2

WageNo

Price

Mixed

100

90

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0

AEs

EMsLIDCs

3.SocialAssistanceProgram

Indexation3

No

Yes,toothervariables

Yes,toin?ation

100

90

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0

AEs

EMsLIDCs

4.PublicWagesIndexation4

No

Yes,toothervariablesYes,toin?ation

AEs

EMsLIDCs

Sources:IMFstaffanalysisbasedonanIMFsurveyandusingadditionaldatafromBeer,Grif?ths,andKlemm(2023);IMFPaySystemsdatabase(2016);InternationalSocialSecurityAssociationdatabase;OECD(2022c);andUSSocialSecurityAdministrationdatabases.

Note:Panelsincludedatafor2016–23.Observationsvaryfrom116to176countriesineachpanel(seeOnlineAnnex2.1fordetails).Priceindexationincludesdifferentmeasuresofin?ation,forexample,“core,”ormeasuresthatincludeonlyurbanworkersorexcludefuel,tobacco,alcohol,andothers.Evenwithautomaticindexation,discretionaryapprovalstagesmaybepartoftheframeworkthatresultinadhocadjustments.AEs=advancedeconomies;EMs=emergingmarketeconomies;

LIDCs=low-incomedevelopingcountries.

1“Regulardefactoadjustments”meansthatpersonalincometaxthresholdsareregularlyrevisedbutnotautomatically.

2“Mixed”indexationreferstoanadjustmentthatincludesamixofprice,wages,andothervariables.

3Socialassistanceprogramsincludemajor?xedcashtransferprograms.“Yes”meansthatmajorityofbene?tsareindexedinthecountry.

4“No”meansthatin?ationdoesnotplayanautomaticormandatoryroleinthesettingofpublicwages.Indexationincludesbothpartialandfullindexation.

EffectsofInflationonPublicFinancesover

theMediumTerm

Inflationsurprisesoftenimprovedebtandbudgetbalancesinthenearterm,butarethesegains

maintainedoverthemediumterm?Toanswerthis

question,thechapteremploysbothquarterlyand

annualdata.7Theeffectsofinflationonpublicfinancecouldebbovertimeforthreemainreasons.First,

7Recentattemptstoanswerthisquestionhaveuseddifferent

methods,includingeventstudies(Blanco,Ottonello,andRanosova2022),model-basedsimulations(Bénassy-Quéré2022),andsurprisesinWorldEconomicOutlookforecasts(October2022FiscalMonitor,

Chapter1).TheUSCongressionalBudgetOffice’s2002workbook

allowsuserstosimulatealternativeeconomicscenariosbyspecifyingdifferentvaluesforinflation(andthreeothereconomicvariables)fortheUnitedStates,comparingthemtoitsbaselineprojections(US

CBO2022b).Theestimatesinthissectionusethelocalprojectionmethod(Jordà2005).Theannualhistoricaldataincludemanymore(emergingmarket)economies,allowingtheresearchofsampleswhereinflationishigher,morevolatile,andlesssurprising(morepersistent).Quarterlydataprovidemoreaccurateestimatesoftheimmediate

effectsofCPIinflationonfiscalvariables.SeeOnlineAnnex2.2.

publicspendingcouldcatchupwithrevenuesthroughindexation.Second,publicpoliciesanddecisions,

includingforwagesorpensions,couldleadtohigher

spendingovertime,reducinganyinitialgainsforpublicfinanceindicators.Third,mostcentralbankshavethe

statutoryobjectiveofmaintainingpricestability,usingadjustmentsintheirpolicyratestodoso,whichmay

leadtoatighteningoffinancialconditionsforagentsintheeconomy,includingthegovernment.Evenso,the

adjustmentofinterestexpensemaybegradualifthe

structureofpublicdebtismostlyinitsowncurrency

andinlongmaturitiesandifthecountry’smonetary

authorityhasareputationformaintainingpricestability.Insuchcases,exchangeraterisksmaybemutedand

marketexpectationswellanchored.Adebtstructure

withlongermaturitieswillfacilitatelesspass-throughofinterestratestoincreasesinpublicinterestpaymentsinthemediumterm.

Analysisusinghistoricalannualdata(1962?2019)for85economiesshowsthat,onaverage,spikesin

4InternationalMonetaryFund|April2023

CHAPTER2INFLATIONANddISINFLATION:WhATROLeFORFISCALPOLICy?

Figure2.2.Reactiontoa1PercentagePointGrowthSpikeintheGDPDe?ator

(PercentofGDP)

1.Debt

0.4

Debt/GDP>50percentDebt/GDP≤50percent

0.0

–0.4

–0.8

–1.2

–1012345

Yearaftershock

2.OverallBalance

Allcountriesinthesample

–1012345

Yearaftershock

0.4

0.0

–0.4

–0.8

–1.2

Source:IMFstaffestimatesusingdatafromtheIMFPublicFinancesinModernHistoryandWorldEconomicOutlookdatabases.

Note:Thedatacovertheperiod1962–2019.FixedeffectsordinaryleastsquaresregressionsusetheGDPde?atorasthein?ationindicatorandinclude85countries.

Countrieswithpopulationsoflessthan1millionin2019areexcludedaswellasobservationswithannualGDPde?atorin?ationhigherthan30percentinabsolutetermsorforwhichtheoriginaldatasourcechanges.Thepanelsplottheaverageimpulseresponseandthe90percentcon?dencebands,withstandarderrorsclusteredatthe

countrylevel.AveragedebttoGDPinthesampleisapproximately50percent.SeeOnlineAnnex2.2.

thegrowthoftheGDPdeflatortendtoreducethe

debt-to-GDPratiopersistently(Figure2.2).8Thedropinthedebt-to-GDPratioislargerineconomieswithhigherinitialdebt,asexpected,withaninitialspikeof1percentagepointinthegrowthoftheGDPdeflator9associatedwithapersistentcumulativedeclineinthedebtratioof0.6percentagepointofGDP(seealso

Chapter1forrecentdevelopmentsontherelationshipbetweeninflationanddebt).ThereductioninthedebtratioiscausedbyahikeintheGDPdenominatorandaninitialriseinfiscalbalances.Thedebtandfiscal

balancereactionstoaspikeinthegrowthoftheGDPdeflatoraresimilarbetweenadvancedandemergingmarketeconomies.Yetthedropindebtissignificantlysmallerincountrieswithflexibleexchangerates,as

inthosecountries,inflationtendstobeassociatedwithexchangeratedepreciation,increasingthevalueofforeign-currency-denominateddebtrelativeto

domesticGDP(seeOnlineAnnex2.2).

8TheresultisqualitativelyrobusttotheuseofCPIinflation.

Tocaptureinflationfromallsources,theestimatesemployordinaryleastsquaresregressions(panelswithfixedeffects).Theanalysis

excludescountrieswith2019populationoflessthan1million.

9Throughoutthechapter,a“spike”ininflationreferstoasuddenriseininflationfollowedbyagradualdecline.Specifically,when

usingannualdata,aspikeisa1percentagepointincreaseinthe

GDPdeflatorgrowthrate,followedbygradualdeclineinsubsequentyears(seeOnlineAnnexFigure2.2.1).Whenusingquarterlydata,thespikeinCPIinflationstemsfroma1percentagepointincreaseincommodityimportinflation(weightedbyGDP),withCPI

inflationpeteringoutafterthreequarters(seeFigure2.4,panel1).

Whereasunexpectedspikesininflationreducethe

debtratio,increasesininflationexpectationsdonot.The

latterareassociatedwithafasterriseinbothprimary

spendingandinterestexpense,andasmallerincreasein

thenominalGDPdenominator.Thedifferenceinthe

effectsofsurpriseversusexpectedinflationislargerfor

countrieswithhighinitialdebtlevels(Figure2.3).Both

resultsunderscorethatattemptingtoinflatepublicdebt

awayisneitheradesirablenorasustainablestrategy.

Ifinflationsurprisesfrequently,agentswilladjust

theirinflationexpectationsaccordinglyanddemand

protectionagainstit,leadingtohigherspreadsowingto

theinflationrisk.

Estimatesusingquarterlydatafromthefirstquarterof1999tothefourthquarterof2019for28advancedeconomiesconfirmthatCPIinflationspikestended

toimprovetheoverallandprimaryfiscalbalancesin

theshortterm(Figure2.4).10High-frequencydata

capturetheimmediateeffectsofinflationonpublic

10Regressionswithquarterlydataareestimatedusing

instrumentalvariables.CPIinflationspikesareinstrumentedby

thechangeinthepricegrowthofthecommodityimportbasket,

alsointeractedwithanexchangeratepegdummy(lagged).

Commoditypricespikestendtobemoresurprisingandtendto

passthroughtopricesofvariousgoodsandservices(seeChoi

andothers2018).Thecorrelationisclearforcountrieswithmore

flexibleexchangerateregimes.Forthesecountries,commodity

importpricerisestendtoleadtoexchangeratedepreciationsand

sotomoreinflation.Thisapproachimpliesthatresultscapture

mainlytheimpactofimportedinflationshocks,whichmaydiffer

fromdomesticallydrivenshocksaffectingtheGDPdeflatormore

directly.SeeOnlineAnnex2.2fordetails.

InternationalMonetaryFund|April20235

FISCALMONITOR:ONThePAThTOPOLICyNORMALIzATION

Figure2.3.DebtReactiontoSurpriseversusExpectedGrowthSpikesintheGDPDe?ator

(PercentofGDP)

Debt/GDP>50percentDebt/GDP≤50percent

1.Surprise

1.2

2.Expected

1.2

0.6

0.0

–0.6

–1.2

0.6

0.0

–0.6

–1.2

–1012345

Yearaftershock

–1012345

Yearaftershock

Source:IMFstaffestimatesusingdatafromtheIMFPublicFinancesinModernHistoryandWorldEconomicOutlookdatabases.

Note:Fixedeffectsordinaryleastsquaresregressionsinclude85countriesduringtheperiodwithavailabledata1992–2019.Countrieswithpopulationoflessthan1millionin2019areexcludedaswellasobservationswithannualsurpriseorexpectedin?ationhigherthan30percentinabsolutetermsorforwhichtheoriginaldatasource

changes.Expectedin?ationisde?nedastheone-year-aheadforecast;surprisein?ationisrealizedminusexpectedin?ation.Thepanelsplottheaverageimpulseresponseandthe90percentcon?dencebands(blueshadedareasandredshort-dashedlines),withstandarderrorsclusteredatthecountrylevel.SeeOnlineAnnex2.2fordetails.

Figure2.4.EstimatedInitialGainstoFiscalBalancesfromCPIIn?ationSpikes

(PercentofGDP,unlessstatedotherwise)

1.CPIIn?ation2.OverallBalance

(Percent)

1.21.2

0.80.8

0.00.0

0.40.4

–0.4–0.4

–0.8–0.8

–1.2–1.2

–101234567–101234567

Quarteraftershock

Quarteraftershock

3.TotalTaxRevenue

1.2

0.8

0.4

0.0

–0.4

–0.8

–1.2–101Qurteraersck567

4.PrimaryExpenditure

1.2

0.8

0.4

0.0

–0.4

–0.8

–1.2

–101234567

Quarteraftershock

5.InterestExpense

0.6

0.4

–0.2

–0.4

–0.6–101Qurteraersck567

6.NominalLong-TermBondRate

(Percent)

0.6

0.4

0.20.0

–0.2

–0.4

–0.6–101Qurteraersck567

Sources:IMFstaffestimatesusingdatafromGrussandKebhaj(2019);Ilzetzki,Reinhart,andRogoff(2019);andIMFInternationalFinancialStatisticsandWorldEconomicOutlookdatabases.

Note:Regressionsareestimatedbetweenthe?rstquarterof1999andthefourthquarterof2019usinginstrumentalvariablesandcontrolforquarterindicatorvariablesandcountryandyear?xedeffects(?xedeffectstwo-stageleastsquares).Thepanelsplottheaverageimpulseresponseandthe90percentcon?dencebands(blueshaded

area)withstandarderrorsclusteredatthecountrylevel.SeeOnlineAnnex2.2fordetails.CPI=ConsumerPriceIndex.

6InternationalMonetaryFund|April2023

CHAPTER2INFLATIONANddISINFLATION:WhATROLeFORFISCALPOLICy?

financebeforepolicieshavetimetoreact.Thefindingssuggestthatforeach1percentagepointinitialincreaseininflation,budgetbalancesgoupby0.5percent

ofGDP.RevenuebroadlyrisesinlinewithnominalGDP,whereasprimaryexpenditurestendtobestableinnominaltermsininitialquarters.Interestexpenseclimbsgraduallyovertimegiventhatdebtinthe

samplefeaturesmainlyfixedratesandlongmaturities,slowingthepickupineffectivenominalratesof

publicbonds.

Thequarterlydatafurtherenableempiricalexercisesforbudgetsubcomponents,revealingdifferentpatternsamongthem(seeOnline

Annex2.2).Whiletotaltaxrevenueinnominaltermsgrowsbyaboutthesamemagnitudeasinflation,someitems(profitandincometaxes)

riseproportionallymore.Ontheexpenditureside,someexpenditurecategoriesaresticky,especially

compensationofemployeesandsocialbenefits.Overtime,automaticordefactoindexationbringsthoseexpendituresbacktotheirinitiallevelsinrealterms.

DistributiveEffectsofInflationand

FiscalPolicySupport

Beyondtheoverallimpactofinflationonthe

fiscalaccounts,analyzingtheeffectsofinflationonthedistributionofhouseholds’well-beingiskey

tounderstandinghowpolicies,includingsocial

protection,canbedesignedtotakesucheffectsintoconsideration.Suchananalysiscanalsobeuseful

forexploringthepoliticalfeasibilityofotherpoliciesorreformsbyidentifyingpotentialpressurepoints(relativewinnersandlosersamongthosewhostandtogainorlosefrominflation).Asthediscussionthatfollowsshows,forexample,theimpactofinflationincountrieswithsizablemortgagemarketsismoreadverse—asashareofhouseholdincome—forthoseolderthanage65(usuallynetholdersofnominal

assets)thanforpeopleintheir30sto40s(whooftenhavemortgagedebtoutstanding).Whenconsideringthedesign,timing,andpreparatoryworkforreformstopensionsorhealthcare,itwouldbehelpfulto

considerthatinflationisalreadyplacingaburdenonthehouseholdsandgroupsthatwouldbemoreaffected.Thissectionuseshousehold-leveldatafordistinctcountriesandeconomicgroupstoexaminesuchdistributiveeffects.

ChannelsforDistributiveEffectsofInflation

acrossHouseholds

Inflationaffectsthedistributionofhouseholds’

well-beingthroughthreemainchannels:11

.Differencesinpriceincreasesacrossgoodscombined

withdifferingconsumptionpatterns(consumption

basketchannel).Ifthepricesofsomegoodsrise

morethanthoseofothers,householdswithahighershareofhigher-pricedgoodsintheirconsumptionbasketswillsuffermore.Forexample,spikesinfoodpricesmayhurttheconsumptionofthepoormorethanotherhouseholdsbecausefoodconstitutesa

largershareofconsumption(andincome)forthepoor(BaezRamirez,Inan,andNebiler2021).Ifinflationbecomesequallywidespreadacrossgoodsandservices,thisdifferentialeffectabates.

.Impactonhouseholds’realincomes(incomechannel).

Realincomesmaybesignificantlyerodedifwages,pensions,orothertransfersdonotkeeppacewith

inflation.Theextentanddistributionofsucherosiondependsnotonlyonfeaturesofthelabormarketandpensionortransfersystemsbutalsoonthesourceofpricechanges.Duringthepricesurgeof2021,whichwasdrivenbycommodityprices,forexample,real

wagesfellinmostcommodity-importin

溫馨提示

  • 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
  • 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶(hù)所有。
  • 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
  • 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
  • 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶(hù)上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶(hù)上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
  • 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
  • 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶(hù)因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。

最新文檔

評(píng)論

0/150

提交評(píng)論