版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶(hù)提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
外文翻譯原文THEINTERNATIONALCOMPETITIVENESSOFHUNGARIANAGRCULTURE:PASTPERFORMANCEANDFUTUREPROJECTIONSMaterialSource:Post-CommunistEconomies,2006(16).Author:MatthewGortona,SophiaDavidovab,MartinBansec,AlistairBaileyd1.Methodology:DomesticResourceCost(DRCs)RatiosWhilethereisalackofconsensusonhow,orifatall,internationalcompetitivenessshouldbemeasured,inpracticetheDRCratiohasbeenwidelyapplied(Tsakok,1990).TheestimationofDRCshasbeenperceivedasusefulincomparingthecompetitivenessofunlikeproductionsystemsandassessingthecomparativeadvantageofalternativeactivities(MonkeandPearson,1989).TheDRCapproachhaspreviouslybeenemployedinassessingtheinternationalcompetitivenessofHungarianagriculture,forthemid-1990s,byBanseetal.(1999)andbyemployingthesamemeasureasthelatterauthorsitispossibletoanalysechangesthatoccurredduringthepre-accessionperiod. ThemainweaknessoftheDRCmeasurehasbeenperceivedtobeitsstaticnaturewhichfailstocapturemarketdynamics(Tsakok,1990).ThisproblemisnotuniquetotheDRCmethodandissharedbymostcost-benefitanalysis.Oneapproachtodealingwiththisweaknessistoconductsensitivityanalysisbyassessingthesensitivityoftheestimatesatvaryingpricesandquantitiesofinputsandoutputs(KannapiranandFleming,1999).2.DRCsEstimatesfor2000to2002Foreachofthearablecrops,corporateenterprisesaremoreinternationallycompetitivethanindividualfarms(asindicatedbylowerDRCratios).Onesubstantialdifferencebetweenindividualandcorporatefarmsistheamountofnon-tradablecostspertonne.Forexample,forwheatproducedbyindividualfarmsin2001,theaveragecostofnon-tradablespertonnewas14,705HUF(€57.3).Thecorrespondingfigureforcorporatefarmswas12,377HUF(€48.73).Differencesinlabourinput,measuredintermsofitsopportunitycost,accountprincipallyforthehigherproportionofnon-tradablecostsonindividualfarms.Sunflowerproductionbycorporatefarmswasinternationallycompetitivein2000and2001andaboutone-thirdofHungary'stotalsunflowercropisexported.Onecompany(CereolRt.)dominatescommercialoilseedprocessingandNemes(2003)reportsthatin2002,Cereoloffereddomesticproducers€277.7pertonne,whiletheaveragef.o.b.exportparitypricewas€206.5(in2001,€241.2pertonnef.o.b.price).Withthedropininternationalprices,exportsfellsignificantly,particularlyasforperiod2000-2002exportsofoilseedsandvegetableoilwerenotsubsidisedbythestate.Hungary'smainmarketsareRussia,Belarus,Poland,BosniaandSlovenia.Hungarianpotatoproductionwasnotcompetitiveinanyoftheyearsstudied.Theareaunderpotatocultivationhasdeclinedsignificantlysincetheearly1990s(in1995nearly70,000hawereplantedcomparedwith34,500hain2002).ProductionisnowconcentratedintheGreatPlainbuteventheretheareaassignedtopotatoesissmallcomparedtoothercrops.Post-accession,itisexpectedthatdomesticproductionwillfurtherdeclineduetosubstitutionbyimportsfromPoland.Hungariantradeinsugarandsugarbeetisquitethinwiththedomesticmarkethighlyregulated.Twotothreecompaniesdominatethesugarindustrywiththevastmajorityofgrowersoperatingoncontractswiththeselargeplayers.Averagesugarbeetyieldsarearound40tperhectare,whichisonaparwiththeCzechRepublicbutlowbyUKandGermanstandards(ZimmermannandZeddies,2002).TheDRCcalculationsindicatethatcorporatefarmproductionwasinternationallycompetitivein2001and2002butgiventhenatureofthemarket,substantialchangesintheareadevotedtosugarbeetarenotexpectedintheshorttomediumterm.Incontrasttoarableproduction,Hungarianlivestockfarmingwasnotinternationallycompetitiveduringtheearlytomid-1990sandBanseetal.(1999)reportedDRCratiosformilkandporkwhichwereconsiderablyabove1.Duringthe2000-2002period,milkproductiononbothcorporateandindividualfarmscontinuedtobeinternationallyuncompetitive.Whiletheproductivityofmilkproductionisnotparticularlylow,asevidencedbytheinput-outputcoefficientsintheCGEmodel,Hungarydependsonhightradesupport(domesticquotas,highimporttariffsandpriorto2001exportsubsidies)tomaintainitsstatusasanetexporter.Theunitvaluesofexportsarelow:togiveanindicationofscale,theadjustedf.o.b.bordervalueofthemilkproducedbyindividualfarmsin2001was64HUF(€0.26)perlitre,comparedtotradableandnon-tradablecostsof35and50HUF(€0.13and€0.19)perlitrerespectively.Themainnon-tradablecostistheopportunitycostoflabourinput.Thislabourinputonindividualfarmsisnon-salaried(ownorfamily)andthusthereisalargedifferencebetweenpaidcostsandtheDRCcalculationswhichaccountfortheopportunitycostsoflandandlabour.Hungary’sunfavourableinternationalposition,particularlycomparedwithSlovakia,inmilkproductionhasbeennotedelsewhere(Udovecz,2001).However,whilemilkcontinuedtobeuncompetitive,chickenproducerswitnessedanimprovementinfortunesduringthe2000to2002periodastheindustryrecoveredfromtheRussiancrisisanddomesticdemandforpoultryexpanded.GermanyandAustriaarecurrentlyHungary'smostimportantexportmarketswithsalestothesetwocountriesrisingsignificantlyaftertheJuly2001agreementwiththeEUtoopenupmarkets.Theindustrybenefitedfromthebumperharvestsin2001and2002:inthe2002marketingyear,feedcostswere10percentlowerthanin2001.Duringthesameperiod,outputalsorose.However,theadoptionofEUregulationsgoverninghygieneandanimalwelfarewillincreasecostsofproduction(Keszietal.2003)andthusdecreasecostcompetitiveness.Inporkproduction,thereremainsalargedividebetweentheinternationalcompetitivenessofindividualandcorporatefarms.Thecompetitivenessofindividualfarmproductiondeterioratedbetween2000and2002asaresultoftheappreciationoftheHUF.Exportershavedependedonstatesubsidies(about20-25percentoftotalHungarianproductionisexported).Exportsubsidiesintheperiod2000to2002forporkrangedfrom27to90HUF(€0.09to€0.39)perkgdependentonthetypeofmeat.Futureproductionisexpectedtoshrinkdramatically,asdomesticsupportswerewithdrawnafteraccessiontotheEU.3. DRCsProjectionsfor2007and2013In2002,onlytheweightedaverageDRCsforsugarbeetandchickenwerebelow1andunderthebaselinescenario(non-accession)whenonlypriceeffectsareconsideredthisdoesnotchangeineither2007or2013.Whilethepriceeffects,principallygrowthinfactorcosts(landandlabour),haveanegativeimpactoncompetitiveness,historicratesofproductivity,ifmaintained,aresufficienttooffsettheadverseeffectofthepricechanges.Forexample,theDRCratioforwheatin2002was1.23butthisfallsto1.0and0.87inyears2007and2013respectivelywhenbothpriceandproductivityeffectsaretakenintoconsiderationinthebaselinescenario.Asimilarpictureisevidentforallothercommoditiesapartfrommilk.Priceeffectsarelargerundertheaccessionscenariothaninthebaselinecase,particularlytherisesinlandandlabourcosts.
Thesepriceeffectshaveasignificantlynegativeimpactoninternationalcompetitiveness:forexample,theDRCratiosforwheatandporkrisefrom1.23and1.38in2002to1.69and1.8in2007and1.94and2.26in2013respectivelywhenonlythepriceeffectsareconsidered.Moreover,whileforthebaselinecase,historiclevelsofproductivitychangewouldbesufficienttooffsetthepriceeffects,thisisnotsoundertheaccessionscenarioforarablecrops.Forexample,theDRCratiosforwheatandmaizein2007areestimatedtobe1.32and1.2respectivelywhenbothpriceandhistoriclevelsofproductivitychangeareconsidered,comparedagainstratiosfor2002of1.23and1.15respectively.Inotherwords,toimproveinternationalcompetitivenessinarableproductionHungarywillhavetoachieveproductivityimprovementsthatareabovehistoriclevelstooffsettheadversepriceeffectsofaccession.Forporkandchicken,historiclevelsofproductivitychangearesufficienttooffsettheadversepriceeffectsofaccessionbecausethemainincreasedcostsassociatedwithaccessionisland,whichaccountsforalowerproportionoftotalcostsfortheseproducts.
However,thesecalculationsdonotaccountforthecostsofanyadditionalinvestmentsthatmayberequiredtomeettherequirementsofEUanimalwelfareandotherlegislation.IfHungaryfollowsSpainandPortugalandbenefitsfromasubstantialriseinproductivitypost-accession,ashypothesisedinthethirdpolicyscenario,internationalcompetitivenesswouldimproveconsiderably.Underthisscenario,theDRCratiosforallcommoditiesarepredictedtobelow1in2007and2013exceptmilk,andpotatoesin2007.By2013,theratiosforwheat,maizeandsunflowerseedsareallpredictedtobesubstantiallybelow1.Ifenhancedproductivitygrowthisachieved,Hungarywillrecaptureorimproveonitscompetitivepositionofthemid-1990s.First,accessionhasamoreadverseeffectontheinternationalcompetitivenessofcropsproducedbyindividualfarmsthancorporateenterprises.Thisisbecausecorporatefarmsusefewerunitsofnon-tradedfactorsofproductionperunitoftradablecoststhanindividualfarms.Themainpriceeffectofaccessionisonland,andtoalesserextent,labour,whicharefarlargerthanchangesinthesocialpricesofoutputsandtradableinputs.Forexample,theDRCratiosforwheatin2007undertheaccessionscenariowithhistoricratesofproductivitychangeareforecasttobe1.72and1.22forindividualandcorporatefarmsrespectively,incontrasttocomparableratiosfor2002of1.51and1.16respectively.Second,withoutenhancedproductivitygrowth,mostoftheoutputofindividualfarmswillremainuncompetitive.Ifunderaccessiononlyhistoricgrowthratesinproductivityareachieved,theninboth2007and2013onlychickenproductionwouldbeinternationallycompetitive.Pork,inparticular,wouldremaindeeplyuncompetitiveandtheratiosforallthecropsareabove1.Incontrast,evenifonlyhistoricratesofproductivitygrowthwereachievedunderaccessionbycorporatefarms,theninadditiontochicken,sunflower,sugarbeetandmaizeproductionwouldbeinternationallycompetitivein2013.Theratioforwheat(1.09)suggests,givenitsclosenessto1,thatthemostefficientcorporatefarmproducingthiscommoditywouldalsobeinternationallycompetitive.Forbothindividualandcorporatefarms,historicratesofproductivitygrowthareinsufficienttoimprovethecompetitivenessofHungarianmilkproduction.4. ConclusionsThispaperanalysesthesocialprofitabilityandinternationalcompetitivenessofHungarianagricultureinthepre-accessionperiodandpresentsaseriesofprojectionsfortheyears2007and2013.Incombininganalysisfortheyears2000to2002,withtheresultsoftheCGEmodelanddifferentassumptionsonproductivitychange,anattempthasbeenmadetodealwiththemostcommoncriticismoftheDRCapproach,thatitisastaticconcept,andassesstheimpactofdynamicchangesinpricesandproductivity.Theanalysisindicatesthatduringtheperiod2000to2002Hungarianinternationalcompetitivenessincropsdeclinedasaresultofappreciationoftheforint,staticdomesticdemandandfallingexportpricesasoutputinotherCEECsrose.Whilelivestockproducersbenefitedfromlowerfeedcosts,milkand,toalesserextent,porkproductionremaineduncompetitive.Thegapininternationalcompetitivenessbetweenindividualandcorporatefarms,apparentinthemid-1990s,haspersisted.譯文匈牙利農(nóng)業(yè)國(guó)際競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力:現(xiàn)狀和規(guī)劃資料來(lái)源:Post-CommunistEconomies,2006(16).作者:MatthewGortona,SophiaDavidovab,MartinBansec,AlistairBaileyd1.方法論:國(guó)內(nèi)資源成本(DRCs)的比率雖然是一個(gè)缺乏共識(shí)的結(jié)論,在所有的衡量國(guó)際競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力的實(shí)踐中,DRCs的比例得到了廣泛應(yīng)用(Tsakok,1990)。DRCs評(píng)估被理解為在比較有用的不同生產(chǎn)系統(tǒng)的競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力和評(píng)估(MonkeandPearson,1989)的替代比較優(yōu)勢(shì)。DRCs法以前就已經(jīng)被用于評(píng)估匈牙利農(nóng)業(yè)國(guó)際競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力,90年代中期,由Banse(1999年)等作家,因?yàn)楹笳卟捎猛瑯拥拇胧┦菍?duì)有可能的變化進(jìn)行分析,在加入前期間發(fā)生的。
DRCs的措施主要弱點(diǎn)時(shí)因?yàn)樗钠潇o態(tài)性質(zhì),未能捕捉市場(chǎng)動(dòng)態(tài)(Tsakok,1990)。這個(gè)問(wèn)題是不是DRCs法特有的,DRCs是由最符合成本效益分析來(lái)處理這個(gè)弱點(diǎn)進(jìn)行了評(píng)估在不同的價(jià)格,投入和產(chǎn)出(Kannapiran和弗萊明,1999年)的數(shù)量估算的靈敏度分析。
2.從2000至2002年的DRCs評(píng)估
對(duì)于農(nóng)作物的耕地,每個(gè)企業(yè)比個(gè)體農(nóng)場(chǎng)(由低金比率表示)更具有國(guó)際競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力。個(gè)人和公司之間的一個(gè)農(nóng)場(chǎng)的本質(zhì)區(qū)別是每噸非流通費(fèi)。例如,對(duì)于個(gè)別農(nóng)場(chǎng)在2001年生產(chǎn)的小麥,非貿(mào)易品每噸平均成本為14705福林(€57.3)。對(duì)企業(yè)農(nóng)場(chǎng)的相應(yīng)數(shù)字是12377福林(€48.73)。在勞動(dòng)力投入的差異,其機(jī)會(huì)成本來(lái)衡量,主要考慮為對(duì)個(gè)體農(nóng)場(chǎng)非流通成本高的比例。
向日葵農(nóng)場(chǎng)生產(chǎn)的企業(yè)國(guó)際競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力,在2000年和2001年約三分之一的匈牙利總向日葵作物三分之一用于出口。一個(gè)公司(CereolRt.)占主導(dǎo)地位的商業(yè)油籽加工及Nemes(2003)的報(bào)告說(shuō),2002年Cereol提供價(jià)格€277.7每噸,而平均離岸價(jià)平價(jià)價(jià)格為€出口206.5(2001年,€離岸價(jià)格每噸241.2)。隨著國(guó)際價(jià)格的下降,出口大幅下降,特別是作為2000-2002年期間油籽和植物油出口量不是由國(guó)家提供補(bǔ)貼。匈牙利的主要市場(chǎng)是俄羅斯,白俄羅斯,波蘭,波斯尼亞和斯洛文尼亞。
匈牙利的馬鈴薯生產(chǎn)競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力還沒(méi)有過(guò)任何一年的研究。根據(jù)馬鈴薯種植面積的大幅下跌,自20世紀(jì)90年代初(1995年種植了近7萬(wàn)公頃,2002年則為34,500公頃)?,F(xiàn)生產(chǎn)主要集中在大平原,但即使在那里分配給土豆面積比較小的其他作物。入世后,預(yù)計(jì)國(guó)內(nèi)產(chǎn)量將進(jìn)一步下降,從波蘭的進(jìn)口,作為替代。
甜菜糖和匈牙利的貿(mào)易是相當(dāng)高度管制和國(guó)內(nèi)市場(chǎng)的薄弱。兩到三家公司主宰隨著與這些大公司經(jīng)營(yíng)合同種植者的絕大多數(shù)制糖業(yè)。甜菜平均單產(chǎn)為每公頃40噸左右,這是一個(gè)與捷克共和國(guó)的標(biāo)準(zhǔn)桿,而且低于英國(guó)和(ZimmermannandZeddies,2002年)德國(guó)標(biāo)準(zhǔn)。DRCs的計(jì)算表明,農(nóng)業(yè)生產(chǎn)是企業(yè)在2001年和2002年的國(guó)際競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力,但由于市場(chǎng)的性質(zhì),用于甜菜面積有很大的變化不會(huì)在短期到中期內(nèi)表現(xiàn)出預(yù)期。與的耕地生產(chǎn)相反,匈牙利畜牧業(yè)國(guó)際競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力的過(guò)程中并沒(méi)有早于90年代中期。Banse(1999年)的DRCs報(bào)告的牛奶和豬肉的比例大大高于1。在2000-2002年間,牛奶公司和個(gè)體農(nóng)場(chǎng)生產(chǎn)仍然在國(guó)際上缺乏競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力。雖然牛奶的生產(chǎn)效率也不是特別低,如在CGE模型的投入產(chǎn)出系數(shù)的證明,匈牙利取決于高貿(mào)易的支持(國(guó)內(nèi)配額,高關(guān)稅和出口補(bǔ)貼在2001年之前),以保持其作為一個(gè)狀態(tài)凈出口國(guó)。出口的單位價(jià)值低:給出的一個(gè)比例顯示,調(diào)整后的離岸價(jià)按個(gè)別農(nóng)場(chǎng)生產(chǎn)的牛奶在2001年邊界值是每公升64福林(€0.26),而流通價(jià)和非流通價(jià)的成本為35和50福林(€0.13€0.19)分別為每公升。主要的非流通價(jià)的成本是勞動(dòng)力投入的機(jī)會(huì)成本。這種對(duì)個(gè)體農(nóng)場(chǎng)勞動(dòng)投入是不受薪(自己或家庭),因此有一間支付的費(fèi)用和DRCs的計(jì)算規(guī)定對(duì)土地和勞動(dòng)力的機(jī)會(huì)成本帳有很大的差異。匈牙利的不利的國(guó)際地位,特別是與斯洛伐克,牛奶產(chǎn)量一直在其他地方被提出來(lái)(Udovecz,2001)。
然而,雖然仍是沒(méi)有競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力的牛奶,雞肉生產(chǎn)商目睹2000年至2002年期間,在財(cái)富的改善,因?yàn)樵撔袠I(yè)從俄羅斯危機(jī)和擴(kuò)大內(nèi)需恢復(fù)家禽進(jìn)口。德國(guó)和奧地利,目前匈牙利與這兩個(gè)最重要的國(guó)家在2001年7月后與歐盟達(dá)成協(xié)議,大幅開(kāi)放市場(chǎng)銷(xiāo)售的出口市場(chǎng)。從豐收得益于2001年和2002年的行業(yè):在2002年銷(xiāo)售年度,飼料成本百分之十,比2001年低。在同一時(shí)期,產(chǎn)量也有所增加。然而,歐盟的管理衛(wèi)生和動(dòng)物福利法規(guī)的通過(guò)將增加生產(chǎn)成本(Keszietal.2003),從而降低成本的競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力。
在豬肉生產(chǎn)方面,個(gè)人農(nóng)場(chǎng)和企業(yè)之間仍存在著國(guó)際競(jìng)爭(zhēng)力的巨大鴻溝。個(gè)別農(nóng)場(chǎng)生產(chǎn)的競(jìng)爭(zhēng)能力惡化,2000年至2002年,是該福林升值的結(jié)果。出口商必須依靠國(guó)家補(bǔ)貼(約占出口總額的是匈牙利總產(chǎn)量約20-25)。出口補(bǔ)貼的期限為2000至2002年豬肉27-90公斤,每福林的肉類(lèi)依賴(lài)型(€0.09€0.39)
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶(hù)所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒(méi)有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒(méi)有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶(hù)上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶(hù)上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶(hù)因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 商業(yè)決策中的數(shù)據(jù)分析與決策支持系統(tǒng)
- 神東公司2025年度派遣員工同工同酬權(quán)益保障3篇
- 二零二五版煤礦基礎(chǔ)施工安全防護(hù)設(shè)施安裝協(xié)議4篇
- 二零二四年廢電池回收與環(huán)保材料生產(chǎn)合作合同范本3篇
- 二零二五版車(chē)輛掛靠管理免責(zé)協(xié)議模板3篇
- 二零二五年度綠色旅游代建工程合同樣本4篇
- 二零二五版綠植租賃與城市綠化項(xiàng)目合作合同3篇
- 2025年度道路路燈照明設(shè)施設(shè)計(jì)與施工監(jiān)理合同4篇
- 2025年度床上用品品牌推廣與營(yíng)銷(xiāo)策劃合同4篇
- 2025年度建筑垃圾資源化利用承攬工程合同范本4篇
- 教代會(huì)提案征集培訓(xùn)
- 高考語(yǔ)文復(fù)習(xí)【知識(shí)精研】《千里江山圖》高考真題說(shuō)題課件
- 河北省承德市2023-2024學(xué)年高一上學(xué)期期末物理試卷(含答案)
- 012主要研究者(PI)職責(zé)藥物臨床試驗(yàn)機(jī)構(gòu)GCP SOP
- 農(nóng)耕研學(xué)活動(dòng)方案種小麥
- 2024年佛山市勞動(dòng)合同條例
- 污水管網(wǎng)規(guī)劃建設(shè)方案
- 城鎮(zhèn)智慧排水系統(tǒng)技術(shù)標(biāo)準(zhǔn)
- 采購(gòu)管理制度及流程采購(gòu)管理制度及流程
- 五年級(jí)美術(shù)下冊(cè)第9課《寫(xiě)意蔬果》-優(yōu)秀課件4人教版
- 節(jié)能降耗課件
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論