國際勞工組織(ILO):發(fā)展中經(jīng)濟體的平臺工作:數(shù)字化能否推動結(jié)構(gòu)轉(zhuǎn)型_第1頁
國際勞工組織(ILO):發(fā)展中經(jīng)濟體的平臺工作:數(shù)字化能否推動結(jié)構(gòu)轉(zhuǎn)型_第2頁
國際勞工組織(ILO):發(fā)展中經(jīng)濟體的平臺工作:數(shù)字化能否推動結(jié)構(gòu)轉(zhuǎn)型_第3頁
國際勞工組織(ILO):發(fā)展中經(jīng)濟體的平臺工作:數(shù)字化能否推動結(jié)構(gòu)轉(zhuǎn)型_第4頁
國際勞工組織(ILO):發(fā)展中經(jīng)濟體的平臺工作:數(shù)字化能否推動結(jié)構(gòu)轉(zhuǎn)型_第5頁
已閱讀5頁,還剩68頁未讀 繼續(xù)免費閱讀

下載本文檔

版權(quán)說明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請進行舉報或認領(lǐng)

文檔簡介

UNIVERSITYOFTHE

WITWATERSRAND,

JOHANNESBURG

SOUTHERNCENTREFOR

INEQUALITY

STUDIES

FUTUREOFWORK(ERS)

SCISWorkingPaperINumber63

Platformworkin

developingeconomies:

Candigitilisationdrive

structural

transformation?

SarahCookandUmaRani|Dec2023

International

Labour

Organization

Platformworkindevelopingeconomies:Candigitalisationdrivestructuraltransformation?

SarahCookandUmaRani

Abstract

Thispaperdiscussestheexpansionorpenetrationofdigitaleconomicactivityinthecontextofdevelopingeconomies,andwhatthismaymeanforeconomicorstructuraltransformationsforcountriesintheglobalSouth.Weaskwhatpossibilitiesnewjobsandformsofworkinthedigitaleconomyhold-inparticularplatformwork-fortheproductivetransformationofeconomiesinwaysthatcontributetoachievingthegoalsofhuman,inclusiveandsustainabledevelopment.Whataretheimpactsonworkandworkersinthisprocess?Thequestionofwhetheradigitaltransformation'canspurdevelopmentand,ifso,howandtowhosebenefit,dependsinlargepartonthenatureofemploymentcreated,andwhetherlabourcanmovetohigher-productivitysectorswhichraiseincomeswhilealsostrengtheningthecapacitytofinancepublicgoodsandservices,includingsocialprotection.Thispaperprovidesasynthesisofliteratureanddebates-conceptual,historicalandempirical-linkingworkinthedigitaleconomywithideasof'structuraltransformation'anddevelopment.Ouranalysisofhistoricalprocessesofstructuraltransformationandoftheconditionsofworkassociatedwithcontemporarydigitalplatformspointstoarangeofobstaclestodevelopmentand,inparticular,thebreakdownoflinksbetweenskills,productivity,valueandwages,limitedcapacityofstatestoinvestinrelevantinfrastructure,andtheconcentrationofcapitalwithaccesstoaglobalsupplyoflabour.Weconcludebyconsideringpolicyactionsthatwouldbeneededtodirectdigitaleconomic

transformationtowardssustainable,fairandinclusivedevelopment.

Muchofthedebateontheimpactofdigitaltechnologiesontheworldofwork(ers)hasbeenspeculativeand,wheresubstantiatedbyempiricalevidence,ithasstemmedprimarilyfromtheglobalNorth'

https://www.wits.ac.za/scis/research-projects/digital-technologies-the-future-of-workers-and-inequality/

).

Keywords:structuraltransformation,developingeconomies,platformwork,digitalisation,workingconditions,

productivity,skills,gender

Introduction

Thispaperdiscussesthepossibilitiesfor'development'indevelopingeconomiesunderconditionswherethepenetrationofdigitaltechnologiesbecomes,orisassumedtobe,aprimedriverofgrowthandemployment.Whatdevelopmentopportunitiesdodigitaljobsoffer,andwhatdotheymeanforthenatureofworkandconditionsofworkers,and,byextension,forlocalornationaldevelopmentpathways?Digitaljobsbroadlyencompassworkusingnewinformationandcommunicationtechnologies,artificialintelligence(AI)andautomation,whetherwithinoroutsidetheinformationandcommunicationtechnologies(ICT)sector.Inthispaper,whilerecognisingtheimportanceofautomationanddigitisationinthewiderdigitaltransformationofeconomies,wefocusprimarilyonworkundertakenonormediatedthroughdigitalplatforms,includinglocation-basedwork(suchasdeliverycouriersanddrivers),ortaskscarriedoutonweb-basedplatforms(from"click-farms"tomachinetrainingthroughbusinessprocessoutsourcing(BPO)andprofessionalservicessuchaslegalorsoftwareprogramming).Whilethereisindeedgrowingevidencethatjobsusingdigitaltechnologiesarecontributingtoeconomictransformation,includinginlowandlowermiddle-incomeeconomies,thequestionremainsastowhether,howandunderwhatcircumstancesthey

areleadingto“development”asvariouslyconceivedandmeasured.

Thesequestionsaredrivenbyaconcernthatdominantanalysesof"digitaltransformation"havemarginalisedthecriticalroleplayedbyemploymentandlabourintheprocessofdevelopmentforlower-incomeeconomies.Inparticular,wenoteasurprisinglackofattentionwithinthefieldofdevelopmenteconomics,whethertheoreticalorempirical,tothelinkbetweendigitaldevelopmentandstructuraltransformation'aswellasalimitedfocusonissuesofemploymentandconditionsofworkfromadevelopingcountryorglobalSouthperspective.Thisisdespiteexcessiveinequalityandjoblessnessinmanysucheconomies.Wherethedevelopmentalimplicationsofdigitaltechnologiesarediscussed,theemphasistendstobeontheirpotentialtoenhanceproductivityandefficiencywithanassumedlinktogrowthanddevelopment,ratherthanonoutcomessuchasemploymentcreation,higherwages

and“decent”work.

ManyanalystsparticularlyfromtheglobalNorthpredictthatadigitalFourthIndustrialRevolutionwillleadtomassivejoblosses(FreyandOsborne,2017),withimpactsvaryingbycountry,orthatautomationwillleadtochangeswithinoccupations,inparticulartheirbreakdownintospecifictasks(Arntz,GregoryandZierahn,2019;ChangandHuynh,2016;FreyandRahbari,2016;NedelkoskaandQuintini,2018).?Thedebateinrelationtodevelopingcountriesoftenprojectsamoreoptimisticview:thatdigitalisationwillcreatejobs,raiseproductivityandcompetitiveness,thusgeneratinggrowthandenablingcountriestomoveupthevaluechain.Whatisneeded,itis

argued,isforcountriestomaketherequiredinvestmentsindigitalinfrastructureandskillswhichcanhelpthemto

1Whilestructuraltransformationhastraditionallybeenanimportantconcernofdevelopmenteconomics,shiftsinthefieldhaveledtotheneglectofsuchquestions,withafocusinsteadatthemicro-level.ExceptionsarefoundintheworkofscholarssuchasDaniRodrikandHa-JoonChang.Relevantresearchoccursacrossanumberofotherdisciplinesandfieldsincludinginformationtechnology,communications,businessandmanagement(seeforexampleFuetal.(2021a,b)andMatthessandKunkel(2020).EconomistsintheglobalNorth(particularlyUSAandEurope)approachquestionsaboutemploymentandproductivityindigitallabourfromanindustrialisedeconomyperspectivewithdifferentconcerns.

2Manyanalystsareconcernedwithemploymentimplications(whetherjobreplacement,taskificationorotherimpacts),butempiricalworklargelydrawsondatafromtheglobalNorth(forexample,BrynjolfssonandMcAfee,2014).Limiteddataisavailabletoanswerthesequestionsinmanydevelopingcountries.

“catchup”-orevento“l(fā)eapfrog”-stagesofgrowth,andthusdrivethestructuraltransformationoftheireconomiestohigherproductivityandwelfare.UnitedNationsIndustrialDevelopmentOrganization(UNIDO),forexample,writesthat“Technologiessuchasarificialinteligence,bigdataanddronescanhelpenterprisesinLDCsleastdevelopedcountries]enhancetheirproductivityandcompetitiveness,andmoveupthevaluechainladderinagriculture,industry,andtheservicessector.Similarly,digitalgoodsandservicestradeenhancestheopportunityfor

smallandmediumenterprisesSMEs)toparticipateinglobaltradeandenhancetheirfinancialinclusion.”

TheseoptimisticnarrativesofadigitalFourthIndustrialRevolutiontendtofocuscentrallyontherolethattechnologyplaysinraisingproductivityanddrivingtransformationsofeconomyandsociety,underemphasisingthequestionofwhetheradigitaltransformationcanchangethestructureofeconomiesinwaysthatleadto“development”,4forexamplethroughdecentworkingconditionsandimprovementsinlivelihoodsecurity.Evidencetodatesuggeststhat,infact,aggregatelabourproductivityhasdeceleratedoverthepastdecadesinOECD(OrganizationforEconomicCooperationandDevelopment)countries,includingtheUnitedStates,andhasdeclinedindevelopingeconomies(Brynjolfsson,RockandSyverson,2019).Inaddition,latesttechnologiesareconcentratedamongasmallshareoffirmsinadvancedeconomies(Baueretal.,2020;Brynjolfsson,RockandSyverson,2019;Dieppe,2020;Tambeetal.,2020),whilefirmsinlow-incomecountriesgenerallydonothaveaccess

tosuchtechnologiesorthecapacitytobenefitfromthem.

DrawingontheexperienceofcountriesandworkersintheglobalSouth,weexploretheevidenceforandlimitationsofsuchanarrative,intermsofboththekindofemploymentandconditionsofworkgenerated,anddriversofgrowthanddevelopmentmorebroadly.Bywayofbackground,wenotethatanyprocessofdigitaltransformationtakesplacewithinabroaderecosystemassociatedwiththeproductionanduseoftechnologies.Thiswouldincludetheminingofessentialmetalsaskeyinputsintodigitaltechnologies,themanufactureofsuchtechnologiesanddevelopmentofassociatedinfrastructure,theautomationordigitalisationofindustrialproductionprocessesandothertraditionalworksectorssuchasfinance,e-commerceandservices,andthemanagementofelectronicwaste(UNCTAD,forthcoming).Thisbroaderecosystemthuslinksalsotoprominentconcernsaboutresourceuse,environmentalsustainabilityandchangingconsumptionpatterns,allofwhichhaveimportantimplicationsforthe

positionofworkandemploymentwithinsustainableandinclusiveeconomicdevelopmentstrategies.

Inaddition,digitalpenetrationindevelopingcountriesoftentakesplaceagainstabackgroundofrelativelyweakstateandinstitutionalcapacity,limitedfiscalresources,excessivelevelsofinequalityandun-orunder-employment,unfavourabletermsofglobalsupplychainintegrationandthegrowingfinancialisationofeconomicactivity.Withinsuchcontexts,Covid-19furtherintensifiedtherapidspreadofdigitaltechnologieswhilemakingvisibletheoftenproblematicconsequencesforworkersandvariousformsofemployment.Theseconsequencesweresometimesdisguisedbehindnarrativesofemployment-creatingopportunitiesandprogresssurroundingthe"digitalrevolution"

(ILO,2021).

3See

/news/technology-driver-structural-transformation-ldcsAccessed:20/01/2023

.

4Whilethemeaningofdevelopmentremainscontested,ithasatcoreanirreduciblegoalofimprovinglivingconditionsofpeople'(Nayyar,2003:62).Suchideaswerecentraltoearlythinkingaboutstructuraltransformation.

Againstthisbackground,thepapercriticallyexaminestheideaof“structuraltransformation”andexploresthepossibilitiesofa“digitaltransformation”generatingsuccessfulstructuralchangeundercontemporarydevelopmentconditions.Bystructuraltransformationwerefertochangesinthesectoralcompositionofproduction,employment,demandandtrade,aswellasthedistributionofincomes,reductioninpoverty,creationofstableandsecurejobs(withbetterworkingconditions),andchangesinsocialandeconomicinstitutionsthatcanbringaboutaproductivetransformationofsociety.Examiningthedigitaleconomywithinthisbroaderunderstandingofstructuraltransformationshouldhelpustoidentifyandassesswhatopportunitiesdigitaltransformationofferstodevelopingcountries,andwhatactionswillbeneededtoshapethesetowardssustainable,fairandinclusivedevelopment.Dothetraditional“stylisedfacts”ofstructuraltransformation-fromagriculturalsubsistencetoindustrialandservicesectoremploymentwithincreasesinproductivityandenhancedwelfare-anylongerapproximatethedevelopmentpossibiitiesortrajcectoriesavailabletoeconomiesintheglobalSouth?Dosectoralororganisationalchangesinducedbydigitalisationhavethecapacitytocreateemployment,enhanceproductivity,raisewagesandcreatedecentjobsassociatedwith"development"?Whatistheroleofskillsinthisprocess?Whatcanbetheroleoftradeunionsornewformsofworkerorganisingandpowerininfluencinggovernmentpoliciesandfirmbehaviour,ensuringthattheycontributetoaproductivetransformationforthesocietyandeconomy?Andhowdoestheexistinglandscapeofdevelopmentandinequalitydeterminethepossibilitiesfor,andshapetheprocess

of,digitalstructuraltransformationas“development”?

Thispaperprovidesasynthesisofexistingresearch,evidenceanddebates-conceptual,historicalandempirical-underpinningideasof“structuraltransformation”anddevelopment,andthedigitalisationoftheeconomy.Ourpurposeistoexplorelinksbetweenthesedebatesfromtheperspectiveofworkandworkers,withafocusonemploymentcreationandconditionsofwork.Section2providesabriefsummaryofkeystrandsintheliteratureonstructuraltransformation-frompost-wardevelopmentmodelstothesuccessfulstructuraltransformationofdevelopmentalstateslargelyinEastAsia.Thisisfollowedbythestalledtransformationsfollowingtherisetodominanceof“neo-liberal”economicpoliciesandglobalisation,andfacilitatedbytherevolutionininformationtechnologies.Section3examineschangingdebatesabouttheroleoftechnologyineconomicdevelopment,bothintheory(fromold“neoclassical”tonew“endogenous”growthmodels)andinpracticeduringtheperiodoftechnologicalchangeassociatedwith"ICTforDevelopment".Section4turnstotherecentphaseofdigitalisation.Wedrawonthestylisedfactsconcerningskillsandproductivity,investmentinhumancapitalandinfrastructure,andtheroleofcapitalandtechnologyinassessinghowdigitalisationand,specifically,workthroughplatforms,hasaffectedtheconditionsofworkandworkers.Section5assessestheextenttowhichkeyfeaturesorstylisedfactsofstructuraltransformationarepresentinthecurrentshiftstowardsadigitaleconomy,andsuggestssomeofthekeypolicies,institutionalarrangementsandregulatorystepsnecessarytolinkdigitalisationtostructuraltransformationasdevelopment.Inconclusion,wepointtothekeypolicyquestionsthatneedtobeaddressedifkeybarriersto

productivetransformationsaretobeovercome.

Structuraltransformation,labouranddevelopment

Structuraltransformationandthesectoralreallocationoflabour

Structuraltransformationrefers,inparticular,tochangesinthestructureofeconomiesassociatedwitheconomicgrowthanddevelopment,withthemainoutcomebeingthereallocationoflabourfromagriculturetowardsmoreproductiveeconomicsectors(manufacturingandservices).Keyfeatures-oftentermed“stylisedfacts”-includehigherlabourproductivity/returnstolabourthroughsectoralandspatialshifts;anincreaseinskillsandhumancapital,leadingtoimprovedincomesandwell-being;ashifttoformaljobsandinstitutionalarrangementsforsocialsecurity;andmoreequitablegrowthanddevelopment.Whatdrivesstructuraltransformationisthesubjectofgreaterdebate,butwouldgenerallyincludesectoralchange(possiblydrivenbytechnology)towardshigherproductivityactivities;changingtermsoftrade;changingpreferences(consumerdemand)asincomesincrease;andskill-biasedtechnologicalchangefollowinghigherinvestmentineducationandskills.Forthepurposeofthispaper,thekeyfeatureofconcernisthereallocationoflabourbetweensectors-particularlywhenlinkedtomorerecent

technologicalchange-andtheimplicationsforproductivity,wagesorincomesandwelfare.

WritingafterthesecondWorldWar,earlydevelopmenteconomiststheorisedthatlabourwouldfollowmoreadvancedeconomiesinmovingfromlow-productivityactivities(subsistenceagriculture)tohigher-productivitymanufacturingandthentoservices(Lewis,1954;SolowandSwann,1956).Theintersectoralshiftoflabourfromlow-productivitytohigher-productivitysectorswouldgenerategrowth,evenintheabsenceofanyincreaseinproductivitywithinsectors.Buildingontheearlier(one-sector)growthmodelofHarrod-Domar,capitalaccumulation,savingsandinvestmentwereseenaskeystounlockinggrowthpotential,withtechnologyandchangesinproductivitytakenasexogenous.Ontheassumptionthatcapitalwouldflowtonewandmoreproductiveinvestmentopportunities,labourwould,inturn,movetotheresultingnewandmoreproductivejobs.Investment

opportunitieswouldreflectanation'scomparativeadvantageandleadcountriestobenefitfromgainsthroughtrade.

InthepoliticalcontextoftheColdWar,Rostow(1960)infusedthesegrowthmodelswithwesternassumptionsof“modernisation”andculturalchangeoccurringthroughindustrialisation.Rostowarguedthatdevelopingcountrieswouldneedtopassthroughalinearorsequentialsetof“stagesofgrowth”inordertoachievethetransformationexperiencedbythethen-industrialisedcountries.Risingpercapitaincomeswouldbeassociatedwithprogresstowards“modernisation”(Fine,2003:202).Increasingproductivityandsavings-providingthecapitalnecessaryforinvestment-andchangesindemandwerethuslinkedtoprocessesofculturalorbehaviouralchange.5Furthermore,aslabourmovedfrompredominantlylow-incomesubsistenceagriculturetohigher-productivityskilledmanufacturingandthenservicejobs,demandwouldincreaseforhigherlevelsofeducationorinvestmentin

whatlatercametobetermed“humancapital?6-thereturnstowhichwouldgenerateyethigherincomesandwell-

5Finealsonotestheassumptionthat“increasesinproductivity,increasingsavingrates,developmentofindustry,andsoon,woulddependuponculturalchanges,notleastentrepreneurialspiritandtheculturalembracingofmarketandwestern

norms”(2003:203).

6Inthe1960s,Schulz(alongwithothereconomistssuchasBecker)developedthetheorythat"humancapital"wasanecessarycomplementtophysicalcapitalanditsabsenceakeyconstrainttodevelopment.

being.Associatedwiththeseshiftswouldbethe“formalisation”ofemployment,andtheevolutionofnew

institutionalarrangements,includingtheextensionofsocialsecurity.

However,itwassoonrealisedthattherewasacriticalmacroeconomicdistinctioninthenatureofunemploymentbetweendevelopedanddevelopingeconomies(Kalecki,1976).Indevelopedeconomies,"unemploymentwaslinkedtoinadequacyofeffectivedemand;indevelopingeconomies,unemployment(under-employment)wasseenasstructural,resultingfrom.…shortageofcapitalequipmentandsupplyofnecessities"(GhoshandRani,2021:2).Inaddition,itbecameclearthattheemploymentproblemcouldnotbesolvedwiththegrowthoftheindustrialsectoralone.Thespatialandsectoralreallocationoflabourwasnotcostless:theso-called"reservearmy"ofrurallabourwasbeingabsorbedintourbanmanufacturingandservicejobsatlowmarginalwages-withthesurplusgeneratedinagriculturesupportingtheconsumptionofnon-agriculturalgoods,thuseffectivelyprovidinganinitial“subsidy”tocapitalanda“safetynet”forworkersmigratingfromthecountryside.RedistributivepoliciesorinterventionstoensuretheprovisionofwhattheInternationalLabourOrganization(ILO)termed"basicneeds"wouldhavetobeintegratedaspartofanydevelopmentstrategyinordertoensureafairdistributionofincomeand

productiveemployment(ILO,2009;IIO,1961).

Atthesametime,otherstructuraleconomistsanddependencytheoristsarguedthatthehistoricalevidencerefutedtheviewofeconomicdevelopmentasproceedingthrough"stages"withauniformpatternlinkedtoariseinincomepercapita.Theyfocusedinsteadonthedependentnatureofcore-peripheryrelationswhichcreateddeterioratingtermsoftradeand“underdevelopment”ofcolonies.CountriesinLatinAmericaandSouth-EastAsiaturnedto“importsubstitutionindustrialisation”(ISI)tobuildupdomesticcapabilitiesandinvestintheircapitalgoodsindustry.InthecaseoftheEastAsianeconomies,thesepoliciesformedanimportantbasisfortheirsubsequent

export-ledgrowth

Structuraltransformationindevelopmentalstates

Despitecontestationabouttheoriesofgrowth,the"stylisedfact"ofstructuraltransformationrelatingtotheinverserelationshipbetweentheshareofemploymentinagricultureandpercapitaGDPhasprovedremarkablyrobustforthosecountrieswhichsucceededinmovingtomiddle-orevenhigher-incomestatus.Inpractice,however,onlyasmallgroupofeconomiessincethemid-twentiethcenturyhavesuccessfullymanagedsuchatransformation,andthesewereprincipallylocatedinEastandSouth-EastAsia.InthoseLatinAmericanandSouthAsiancountrieswheretherewasinitiallyarapidexpansionofthemanufacturingsectorassociatedwithISI,progresssubsequently

stalledandcreatedaduallabourmarket(GhoshandRani,2021).

Countriesthatsucceededinachievingrapidgrowthinthepost-wardecadeswerelargelythosethatsharedintheEastAsian“exportled”development“miracle”ofthe1960sand1970s.MuchhasbeenwrittenaboutthedevelopmentpathwaysoftheNICs(newlyindustrialisedcountries)andmuchcontroversyhasbeengeneratedoverthedriversoftheirsuccess.Whatisclearisthatcountriesthatsucceededwithsuchatransformationdidsothroughheterogeneouseconomicpathwaysandundervariedpolicyregimes.TheEastAsian"miracleeconomies"owed

theirstructuraltransformationandrapidindustrialgrowth,inpart,toasuccessfultransitionfromimport

substitutionindustrialisation,throughwhichtheybuilttheircapitalgoodsindustriesandinnovationcapacity,toanexport-orientedindustrialstrategy.Despiteeffortstoclaimtheirsuccessasmarket-led(WorldBank,1993),rigorousscholarshiphasshownthatactivedevelopmentalstatesintervenedwitharangeof“selective”industrialandcomplementarysocialpoliciestoshapethisdevelopmenttrajectory(see,forexample,Amsden,1989;Amsdenetal.,2012;Chang,2002).Whatemergesfromtheworkoftheseandotherauthors(forexample,Wade's1996critiqueoftheWorldBank'sEastAsianMiraclereport)isthecriticalroleplayedbythestateindirectingcapitalthrough“selective”industrialpolicies,inducing“patientlabour”throughrepressedwagedemandsandconsumption,whilealsoensuring“patientcapital”thatinvestedforthelongterminproductivecapacitiesaswellasinhumancapitalandsocialinfrastructure.Socialpoliciesinthesestateshadaproductivistorientation,“helpinglosers”while

enhancingthelabour,educationandskillsneededforindustrialisationandinnovation.

So,whilesomebroadstylisedfactsofstructuraltransformationheld,thisoccurredthroughtheoperationofquitespecificpolicyregimesandinstitutionalarrangements.Wheredevelopmentdidoccur,thestateplayedakeyroleinregulatingwagesandworkingconditions,andholdingcapitaltoaccount,whileworkerorganisingsubsequentlybecameanessentialelementofstrugglestoimprovewagesandworkingconditionsandclaimlabourandsocial

rights.

Structuraltransformationunderglobalisation:Stalledindustrialisationandtheshifttoservices

Manydevelopingcountries,bycontrast,failedtoundergoaproductivestructuraltransformationandfoundthemselvesinasituationofstalledindustrialisation,orwhatRodrik(2015)morerecentlytermed"prematuredeindustrialisation”,withexcessivelyhighratesofunemployment,workthatispredominantlyclassifiedasinformal,“wageless”growth,inadequatesocialprotectionandinsufficientsavingsandinvestment.Anumberoffactorshelptoexplainthisfailure.Bhaduri(1989)arguesthatthefailuretomovelabourfromagriculturetotheindustrialsectorinmanydevelopingeconomies,inpart,reflectsinequalityinlandownershipandotherresources.Thispromptedamassiveoutmigrationofagriculturalworkersseekingworkfromruralareastourbanareas,wheretheymovedintolow-skilledindustrialorserviceactivitiesasasurvivalstrategy.Aspatialreallocationoflabourwasaccompaniedbyasectoralshift,butnottohigher-productivitymanufacturing.Instead,themovewasfromagriculturetolow-skilledandlow-incomeserviceactivities.Lookingatthepost-1990periodofglobalisation,McMillan,RodrikandVerdusco-Gallo(2014)similarlyclaimthatstructuralchangeinAfricaneconomieshasmovedlabourintolow-

income,informalemployment.

Otherexplanationsrelatetothebroadercontextoftheriseofneoliberalisminwesterneconomies,andassociatedpoliciesthatfostermarketliberalisationandglobalintegration.Countriesattemptingastructuraltransformationfromthe1980sthusdidsounderverydifferentcircumstancestothoseanalysedbyearlydevelopmenteconomistsorthatexperiencedbytheNICs.First,theriseofneoliberalismasadominantideologyemphasisingmarket-ledgrowthledtothestatebeingviewedasaninefficientbarriertoeconomictransformation.AsNayyar(2003:62)noted,whiletheearlydevelopmentliterature"emphasisedeconomicgrowthandcapitalaccumulationatamacrolevel;contemporaryliteratureondevelopmentstresseseconomicefficiencyandproductivityincreasesatamicro

level”inkeepingwithaneo-liberalemphasisonsupplysidepoliciesandtheprimacyofmarkets.AsNayyaralso

argues,thisreflectsawiderfailureof“mainstreameconomics”todistinguishbetweenmeans(productivity,

efficiency)andends(suchasfullemploymentorpovertyeradication).

Second,whilestructuraltransformationwasconceptualised,policiesimplementedandtheirresultsmeasuredatanationallevel,theroleofthenationstateinthisperiodwaschallengedbyboththedominantmarket-ledideologyandbyglobalisation.Thisphaseofglobalisationunderminedthecapacityofstatesinrelationtoglobalcapitalandinrelationtoadvancedeconomiesandtheinternationalfinancialinstitutions(IFIs).Capitalbecameincreasinglymobilewhilelabourwasconstrained.Capitalflightlimitedwhatcouldbereinvestedtocontributetonationaldevelopment.Stateshadfewerresourcesandlesspolicyspacetodevelopnationalandindustrialpoliciesinlinewiththeirownneeds,withtheirpoliciesdisciplinedbythestructuraladjustmentandstabilisationprogrammesthrough

whichtheIFIsimposedneoliberalism.

Third,tradeandmarketliberalisationdidnotdelivertheexpectedbenefitsformanydevelopingcountries.Intheory,countriesthatliberalise

溫馨提示

  • 1. 本站所有資源如無特殊說明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
  • 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
  • 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁內(nèi)容里面會有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
  • 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
  • 5. 人人文庫網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲空間,僅對用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護處理,對用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對任何下載內(nèi)容負責。
  • 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當內(nèi)容,請與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
  • 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準確性、安全性和完整性, 同時也不承擔用戶因使用這些下載資源對自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。

評論

0/150

提交評論