版權(quán)說(shuō)明:本文檔由用戶提供并上傳,收益歸屬內(nèi)容提供方,若內(nèi)容存在侵權(quán),請(qǐng)進(jìn)行舉報(bào)或認(rèn)領(lǐng)
文檔簡(jiǎn)介
1、corporation as a crucial ally against corruption reyes caldern, jos luis lvarez arce and silvia mayoral school of economics and business administrationuniversity of navarra. campus universitario s/n. 31080 pamplona (spain)rcalderonunav.es, jlalvarezunav.es, smayoralunav.escorporation as a crucial al
2、ly against corruption abstractmanuscript type: empiricalresearch question/issue: this paper aims to contribute to an improved theoretical and empirical understanding of the role that corporation has to play in anticorruption efforts. research findings/insights: using cross-country data from three da
3、tabases (bribe payers index, corruption perceptions index and doing business) we found that pro-bribery investment climate conditions in host countries are not related to the payments of bribes by multinational companies when these corporations operate abroad.theoretical/academic implications: after
4、 describing the conceptual and policy framework that surrounds the discussion on the role played by firms in anticorruption, we present the current debate regarding the effectiveness of international bribery control instruments, with the world bank-gac (2006-8) report as a basis. both literature and
5、 policy seem to be divided into two main, although not mutually exclusive, positions: one demands improvements in investment climate conditions from a joint public-private consensus led by international agencies; the other one supports the effectiveness of self-regulation by firms, independently of
6、investment climate improvements. the study provides empirical support to the idea that a better investment climate is not enough for reducing corruption. practitioner/policy implications: this study offers insights to policy makers interested in promoting the involvement of corporations in the fight
7、 against corruption. introductionthis paper aims to contribute to an improved understanding of the role played by corporations in economic corruption, with the current world bank governance and anticorruption report (wb-gac, 2006-8) as a basis. with this purpose, we first provide a description of th
8、e conceptual and policy framework, and an overview of the current debate surrounding the issue.economic corruption refers to a public official distributing commodities or allocating resources who views his/her office as a private source of gains (jain, 2001; rose-ackerman, 1999). bribery, which resu
9、lts from demand the bribe taker and supply the bribe giver, is best understood and combated if both sides are simultaneously dealt with (berkos, 1999). even this being the case, for decades, policy and research primarily addressed the demand side, while the supply side, usually associated with multi
10、national corporations (mncs) depicted as the innocent party, received little attention (macmurray, 2006; beets, 2005; vogl, 1998). we explain why some factors, like the increasing costs and risks of corruption (aidt, 2003), pressures from stakeholders (waddock et al, 2002) and poor anticorruption pe
11、rformance (vernon et al, 2005), are gradually expanding the focus from demand to demand-supply factors (sung, 2005). in this new scenario the corporation is called to participate as a “crucial ally” (wb-gac, 2006:ii) and a “key pillar of integrity” (un, 2004:83). subsequently, we examine the current
12、 debate, which is raising many related questions regarding the selection and implementation of international bribery control instruments: can societies rely on individual company policies or on industry self-regulation? are other means such as laws or statutes needed? must the public sector lead the
13、 process?at the forefront of this debate we find two variables: the firms vulnerability to the investment climates (ic) characteristics and the leadership of the joint public-private coalition for reform. both have divided literature and policy in two main, but not mutually exclusive, positions. one
14、 demands a join public-private consensus led by international agencies, and ic improvement as a precondition. the other supports the effectiveness of self-regulation, and its independence of ic improvement 1.we offer some empirical evidence on the issue. using the “bribe payers index” (bpi), the “co
15、rruption perception index” (cpi) by transparency international (ti), and the “doing-business” (db) database by the world bank (wb), we test the correlation between the propensity of mncs to pay bribes when operating abroad and the pro-bribery ic conditions in host countries. our results suggest a lo
16、w significance of ic factors in bribe-taking behavior at the country level. therefore, we conclude that the improvement of ic is not enough to reduce bribery. the structure of this paper is as follows. we first provide the theoretical framework, describing factors that explain the growing interest i
17、n the supply side of corruption. then we carry out a critical description of wb-gac, emphasizing the roles assigned to ic and corporation. after that, we discuss the debate and main positions regarding the selection and implementation of anti-bribery instruments. in the last section, we describe the
18、 empirical analysis and show our results. findings are then discussed, and the final section examines some limitations of our analysis as well as possible venues for future research. the supply side of anticorruption effortsmost research and conventions on anticorruption adopt demand-pull perspectiv
19、es (macmurray, 2006; sung, 2005; vogl, 1998). although observers vouch for the generalization and extension of bribery$1 trillion in 2003 (wbi, 2004), with the corporation ranked as the most corrupt institution in countries like hong kong or the netherlands (global corrupt barometer, 2004), strategi
20、es have largely neglected the role played by bribe givers. with few exceptions the “foreign corrupt practices act” (fcpa, 1977) and the oecds “convention on combating bribery of foreign public officials in international business transaction” (oecd, 1997), which will be discussed afterwards, all coun
21、tries criminalize and punish corrupt officials, while sanctions for paying bribes remain rare (rose-ackerman, 2002).the insistence on addressing the demand side was based on two elements: the supposed efficiency of demand-pull instruments, and all the problems associated with attempting to regulate
22、the supply side.the demand-side perspective is built on one key assumption: there is a systemic failure, symptom of the states fundamental weaknesses, which can be efficiently combated by different means: ethical development in the public sectors infrastructure (berkos, 1999); better legislative act
23、ions and law enforcement (dollar and levin, 2006); stronger and more effective public institutions (huang and wei, 2006); accountability and transparency requirements (everett et al, 2007); and privatization and decentralization (caselli and morelli, 2004). authors add the positive impact of governm
24、ent on wealth promotion (husted, 1999), the reduction of inequality (you and khagram, 2005), the control of extractive industries (ohiggins, 2006), and the support of an anti-corruption culture (sanyal, 2005). this spirit is clearly seen in the inter-american convention against corruption (1996), wh
25、ose preamble proposes “especially action against persons who commit acts of corruption in the performance of public functions”. when focusing on supply-side instruments, however, some difficulties emerge. one of these is the likelihood of a “race to the bottom” effect in cross-country competition fo
26、r doing and attracting business. while some countries impose strict laws on domestic firms competing for offshore business, others are reluctant. the us department of state claims that, due to this factor, between 1994 and 2001, american business lost 400 major contracts (sung, 2005). on the other h
27、and, the corporation is constituted as a legal person, for whom only dissuasive non-criminal sanctions are applicable (ocde, 1997:art. 3). moreover, the literature shows strong technical problems related with data and aggregation, due to the heterogeneity of the supply (dollar et al, 2005). these fa
28、ctors explain why only one main instrument the disallowing of the tax deductibility of bribes has obtained consensus.however, a new sensibility seems to be emerging. all the involved agents now agree that corporations have a main role to play in promoting transparency and curbing corruption. the wb-
29、gac names the corporation a “crucial ally against corruption” and the un (2004:84) considers it as a “key pillar of integrity”.poor results of anticorruption efforts explain this new view. after two decades of emphasis on demand-side elements, corruption has not dissipated and improvements have most
30、ly stagnated (veron et al, 2006). policymakers and academia have finally become convinced that “governments alone cannot contain corruption” (un, 2004: 17). “traditional public sector intervention is not enough in tackling challenges. wider engagement with the domestic private sector and mncs is req
31、uired” (wb-gac, 2006: introduction).impelled by stakeholder pressures and the perceived costs and risks, the corporation has accepted its new role. bribery and corruption are nowadays among the great issues on corporate governances agenda (elkington, 2007). although corrupt practices can be benefici
32、al for some individual firms, corruption increases costs and risks for the whole. in contrast with free markets and quality institutions, corruption increases transaction and doing-business costs (pantzalis et al, 2007). with insecure property rights, high risk of expropriation and low reliability o
33、f contract enforcement, the number and size of firms (beck et al, 2005), foreign investment (mauro, 1995), profit per firm (ades and di tella, 1997), long-term performance (baucus and baucus, 1998), and quality of produced goods (nwabuzor, 2005) are reduced. gjessing and syse (2007) signal that inve
34、stors recognize the additional risk, and attempt to ensure the corporation has sufficient internal controls while top management supports and implements relevant anticorruption rules. enron and its sequels have reinforced the main hypothesis: it is in the best interest of the private sector to apply
35、 self-imposed anticorruption measures (howlett and rayner, 2006).additionally, in light of a wide range of events linked to labor, health and safety rights (belcher, 2002) and environmental concerns (elkington, 2007), broad discussions have emerged to address the role of the corporation in society,
36、its ethical standards, corporate governance practices and management decisions systems (bonn and fisher, 2005). as a result, primary and external stakeholders around the world compel companies “to respond in a more responsible and transparent way to environmental pressures” (waddock et al, 2002: 132
37、). due to growing evidence of rampant consequences of bribery on development, poverty, inequality and human suffering2, anticorruption has become a “hot issue”. the new framework: wb-gac (2006-08).some evidence of change may be perceived in the “new generation” of anticorruption strategies (coleman
38、and perl, 1999), such as the wb-gac. in comparison to past reports fcpa (1977) and ocde (1997), which simply conceptualized the corporation as the agent who pays bribes, the wb-gac includes a multidisciplinary approach, focusing on governance and ic.fcpa (1977), which makes extraterritorial bribery
39、explicitly illegal for us companies and creates requirements for greater transparency, and oecd (1997), an attempt to extend sanctions around the world, present three main coincidences: - both try to legally avoid corrupt behavior. like rose-ackerman (2002), they consider that a firms main argument
40、to reject corruption is their status as a legal person operating at the state suffrage. attitudes or values, which have been essential in countries like hong kong, are largely neglected. - while both welcome the contribution of companies, the role of self-regulation and private codes is left unaddre
41、ssed.- both recognize the role that governments play in the prevention of bribe solicitation, but neglect the analysis of the ics impact.contrarily, the wb-gac (a) refuses the monopoly of legal focus, admitting that champions of reform may be found inside and outside the executive branch of governme
42、nt, including the business community; (b) names the corporation a “crucial ally”; and (c) focuses especially on the improvement of the ic. addressing the private sector, the wb-gac (2006: 12-14) begins describing the divergence of incentives. in the middle and long-term, corruption increases vulnera
43、bility and uncertainty for firms, and has a detrimental impact on their dynamism and growth. consequently, mncs have a strong incentive to reject venal officials as strategic partners. but in the short-term, corruption creates lucrative opportunities with low risk for unethical corporations. many pr
44、ivate businesses, “including some from developed countries, themselves engage in corrupt practices” (wb-gac, 2006:12).if integrity and incentives were always positively correlated, debate would be superfluous (rose-ackerman, 2002). however, divergences affect firm behavior. thus, in order to deter t
45、he last type of behavior and to fuel the first, the wb-gac establishes three type of actions. 1. actions from government to private sector. the report recognizes the main role played by the ic and indicates that some ic features make firms vulnerable to corruption in host countries. thus, it propose
46、s to help governments to “eliminate excessive red tape and non-transparent regulations, reduce monopolistic practices, transparently and competitively privatize state-owned business and banks, facilitate the entry of small and medium enterprises” (wbg, 2006:12). 2. actions that encourage a joint pub
47、lic-private coalition for reforms. a public leadership coalition, with “the international financial corporation and multilateral investment guarantee agency working directly with the private sector to introduce ethical corporate practices” (wbg, 2006: 12). 3. public sanctions. measures to raise the
48、cost to businesses that continue to engage in corruption. the wb-gac is already in force. its term, commencing in 2006, is proving itself to be long and problematic. it has included a wbg-imf forum; internal and external feed-back, and consultation with governments, donor agencies, etc. the last ver
49、sion (october 2007) will likely be definitively approved in 2008. some factors related with ic and firms have been in dispute. for example, while in the last version transparency continues to be demanded, references to red tape and monopolistic practices have disappeared and national conditions have
50、 come to the forefront: each country “will have explicit governance indicators to monitor for positive change” (p. 18). in fact, a critical question remains: must the ics improvement and rigorous international monitoring be correlated? can corporation collaboration be required without assuring the c
51、ollaboration of host countries? a second conflictive factor is the reform-leading agent. in the cited feedback, some countries have refused the multilateral approach in an attempt to minimize the business sectors contribution, as the next comment shows: “the private sector have vested interests of t
52、heir own (money-making), and this will hamper aid effectiveness to a great deal” respondent type: government; region: south asia.the debate around mechanismsthe new generation of anticorruption effort is built on the involvement of both private and public actors, which, being not mutually exclusive,
53、 must cautiously work to develop measures that harmonize law, social and national interests, self-regulation, firm freedom, etc. (jordan et al, 2005). in the achievement of the ultimate objective the reduction of bribery through a mix of supply-demand instruments discussions have focused on two diff
54、erent elements:a) who must lead the effort of developing initiatives, defining standards, adopting rules that force corporations toward integrity and monitoring important exporters and producers.b) the obligatory character of removing impediments that make corporations victims of their environment.i
55、n relation with these questions, we identify two positions: the bribery environment position, which requires ic improvements and a joint public-private consensus led by international agencies, and the bribe giver position, which defends the effectiveness of the corporations self-regulation, independ
56、ently of ic improvement. the bribery environment positionthis position maintains that an individual official may not change pro-bribery ic elements, neither an individual corporation is able to impact the national culture and law (schechter, 2007). whereas legal deterrence through legal sanctions ma
57、y be needed to succeed (zang, 2007; sung 2005), or “practices are so ingrained in a culture that there seems to be neither need nor realistic opportunity for change overnight” (gjessing and syse, 2007: 431), any substantial progress requires the collaboration between the global corporation and the h
58、ost countries (potts and matuszewski; 2004). this is in conformity with bthoux et al (2007), who find that business codes attempt to prohibit bribery, referring to types of conduct that violate public regulations and law. this position underlines that public-private collaboration could require the a
59、cceptance of external actors such as international agencies. following the us example, all the developed european and american exporting countries have introduced domestic legislation following oecd (1997), and even un (2004) conventions. many former bribery-tolerant industrialized countries (i.e., france and germany) have rectified and now reject the tax-deductibility of bribes. however, commitment cannot be measured by simple participat
溫馨提示
- 1. 本站所有資源如無(wú)特殊說(shuō)明,都需要本地電腦安裝OFFICE2007和PDF閱讀器。圖紙軟件為CAD,CAXA,PROE,UG,SolidWorks等.壓縮文件請(qǐng)下載最新的WinRAR軟件解壓。
- 2. 本站的文檔不包含任何第三方提供的附件圖紙等,如果需要附件,請(qǐng)聯(lián)系上傳者。文件的所有權(quán)益歸上傳用戶所有。
- 3. 本站RAR壓縮包中若帶圖紙,網(wǎng)頁(yè)內(nèi)容里面會(huì)有圖紙預(yù)覽,若沒有圖紙預(yù)覽就沒有圖紙。
- 4. 未經(jīng)權(quán)益所有人同意不得將文件中的內(nèi)容挪作商業(yè)或盈利用途。
- 5. 人人文庫(kù)網(wǎng)僅提供信息存儲(chǔ)空間,僅對(duì)用戶上傳內(nèi)容的表現(xiàn)方式做保護(hù)處理,對(duì)用戶上傳分享的文檔內(nèi)容本身不做任何修改或編輯,并不能對(duì)任何下載內(nèi)容負(fù)責(zé)。
- 6. 下載文件中如有侵權(quán)或不適當(dāng)內(nèi)容,請(qǐng)與我們聯(lián)系,我們立即糾正。
- 7. 本站不保證下載資源的準(zhǔn)確性、安全性和完整性, 同時(shí)也不承擔(dān)用戶因使用這些下載資源對(duì)自己和他人造成任何形式的傷害或損失。
最新文檔
- 臺(tái)階課文教學(xué)課件
- 四季之美課件77
- 收到以物抵債的設(shè)備賬務(wù)處理實(shí)例-記賬實(shí)操
- 國(guó)際金融教案
- 小學(xué)硬筆書法課件教學(xué)
- 智慧物流園解決方案
- 2023年農(nóng)業(yè)航空作業(yè)裝置項(xiàng)目評(píng)價(jià)分析報(bào)告
- 2024年破傷風(fēng)類毒素項(xiàng)目評(píng)估分析報(bào)告
- 采購(gòu)合同管理自查報(bào)告
- 畢業(yè)生就業(yè)協(xié)議書學(xué)前教育
- 魏晉南北朝服飾課件
- (完整版)污水管網(wǎng)工程施工組織設(shè)計(jì)
- 可可脂巧克力課件
- 阿爾卡特ALKT4400說(shuō)明書
- 體育生大學(xué)生涯規(guī)劃書范文(5篇)
- 交通連四方 杭州交通的發(fā)展課件
- 梨樹栽培技術(shù) 課件
- 2022年常州市工會(huì)系統(tǒng)招聘考試筆試試題及答案解析
- 第13講 教學(xué)設(shè)計(jì)的ASSURE模式(V5.1)公開課一等獎(jiǎng)省優(yōu)質(zhì)課大賽獲獎(jiǎng)?wù)n件
- 三年級(jí)上冊(cè)美術(shù)課件-3.色彩的變化|贛美版 (共19張PPT)
- 上海高中語(yǔ)文課文目錄
評(píng)論
0/150
提交評(píng)論